How Interest Rates Help Promote Saving and Investing

In modern economies, some individuals earn more money than they need to spend on present goods. There are other individuals who have a desire for more money than they can presently access. A natural market arises between those who have a surplus of present funds (savers) and those who have a deficit of present funds (borrowers). Savers, investors, and lenders are only willing to part with money today because they are promised more money in the future—it’s the interest rate that determines how much more.

Key Takeaways

  • Interest rates can determine how much money lenders and investors are willing to save and invest.
  • Increased demand for loanable funds pushes interest rates up, while an increased supply of loanable funds pushes rates lower.
  • Central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, manipulate interest rates to influence monetary policy.

Supply and Demand for Loanable Funds

The interest rate describes how much borrowers need to pay for loans and the reward that lenders receive on their savings. Like any other market, the market for money is coordinated through supply and demand. When the relative demand for loanable funds increases, the interest rate goes up. When the relative supply of loanable funds increases, the interest rate declines.

The demand for loanable funds is downward-sloping and its supply is upward-sloping. The natural rate of interest in an economy balances out this supply and demand. This mechanism sends a signal to savers about how valuable their money could be. Similarly, it informs possible borrowers about how valuable their present use of the borrowed money needs to be to justify the expense.

The natural rate of interest is mostly a theoretical construct in contemporary economies. Central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, manipulate interest rates to influence monetary policy. For example, a central bank can make it cheaper to borrow and less valuable to save by lowering interest rates in the economy. These actions change the intertemporal incentives faced by economic actors.

Capital Structure and the Economy

Suppose an entrepreneur wants to start a new manufacturing company. The entrepreneur cannot start generating sales until the factors of productionsuch as factories and machines, are in place and operational. This production framework is sometimes referred to as the business capital structure.

Most entrepreneurs don’t have enough money saved up to purchase or build factories and machines. They usually have to borrow the startup money. It can be easier to borrow money if the interest rate is low as it costs less to pay back. If the interest rate is so high that the entrepreneur isn’t convinced that they can earn enough to pay it back, the business may never get off of the ground.

This is how the interest rate helps determine the overall capital structure of the economy. There have to be enough savings for all of the houses, factories, machines and other capital equipment. Additionally, the subsequent capital structure has to be profitable enough to pay back the lenders. When this coordinating process malfunctions, asset bubbles can form and whole sectors can be compromised.

Liquidity Preference Vs. Time Preference

Economists disagree about the exact nature of interest rates. Interest rates have to coordinate past and future consumption, and they place a premium on risk and the safety of liquidity. This is essentially the difference between liquidity preference and time preference.

Related Posts